Vijay K. Mathur
Published
in Standard-Examiner, August 11, 2013, Ogden, Utah
The Corruption
Perception Index (CPI) of Transparency International (TI) measures perceived
level of public corruption in countries around the world from the perspective
of businesses and country experts. The rankings are from least to most corrupt.
In 2012, Denmark was the least corrupt while Somalia was the most corrupt among
174 countries. In 2012, the U.S. ranked 19 as compared to 22 in 2010, not a
significant change. On the Bribery Payers Index of TI for 28 countries,
Netherland ranked 1 with the least bribery, the U.S. ranked 10th, and the most
bribery prone country is Russia. The Global Corruption Index of TI surveys
114,000 people around 107 countries. In 2013, 64 percent of the respondents
thought that just a few big interests run the U.S. government.
Corruption implies
dishonesty, bribery, fraud, cheating and perversion of integrity. On different
indices, it seems that U.S. standing on corruption is very poor among the
nations of the world. It has also infected the private sector as we witnessed fraudulent
practices in the banking and financial investment industry, including hedge
funds, derivatives and mortgage finance, in the recent Great Recession. These
practices still continue. As recently as July 25, SAC Capital Advisors, a hedge
fund, was indicted in New York for “rampant insider trading” and charged that
the firm had a culture of pervasive cheating.
Utah is no exception,
as evidenced by cases of affinity fraud in which investment fraud is committed
by using church connections, securities fraud, as well as fraud cases in other
sectors. Public officials are also not immune to fraudulent activity. Utah Attorney
General John Swallow is facing scrutiny for accepting bribes from an imprisoned
businessman. Creeping corruption corrodes moral and ethical standards, fair
play in public policy and in the conduct of business. It also undermines trust
in public officials and in the market place.
Corruption diverts
resources from productive activities, discourages entrepreneurship and
encourages rent seeking behavior, where rewards flow to those who have inside
connections within business world and/or with public officials and politicians.
Hence, it results in efficiency loss that is detrimental to growth and
prosperity for all the people. The 1999 report by the European Bank for
Reconstruction and Development provides evidence on deleterious effects of
corruption on growth in many countries.
The worst part of
corruption is its contagion effect, like a contagious disease. There is a
cascading effect of corruption, when the corruption is top down at any level of
government or in private sector. A contagious disease spreads from one person
to another by mere exposure to the diseased person. The spread of the disease
of corruption requires a certain minimum level of corruption before it spreads
to others and becomes the social norm. However, it is hard to pinpoint the minimum
threshold because it is influenced by cultural traditions, lack of monitoring
and accountability, lack of transparency and an incentive system that includes
rules, regulations and laws.
Economists C.J.
Waller, T.Verdier and R.Gardner, Economic Inquiry, October 2002, theorize that
centralized corruption (top down corruption) of public officials (as in Russia)
results in less efficiency loss than bottom up corruption (as in India). The
U.S. is closer to the centralized corruption regime.
The experimental
work, reported by economists Robert Innes and Arnab Mitra (IM), Economic
Inquiry, January 2013, at U.S. universities and at a university in India shows
that dishonesty is contagious. An Indian experiment found that if a large
proportion of the subjects were dishonest, other individuals were also
dishonest with greater frequency. In the U.S., “... individual
propensities for honesty evaporate when peers are thought to be dishonest.”
The above evidence is
remarkable in the sense that it does not matter if the country is more corrupt,
like India (ranking 94 on CPI in 2012) or China (ranking 80 on CPI in 2012), or
less corrupt like the U.S. IM argue that their findings also provide some hope
that corruption can be reduced, if there are significant number of honest peers
to establish the social norm of honesty, integrity and truthfulness.
Chrystia Freeland, in
her book “Plutocrats,” refers to a study in a book by Daron Acemoglu and James
Robinson (AR) that analyses rise and downfall of nations. AR argue that the
difference between failed states and successful states is “whether their
governing institutions are inclusive or extractive.” In extractive states,
ruling elites exercise control.
The ruling elite’s
aim is to acquire power and maximum amount of wealth from the rest of the
society.
Concentration of
power and wealth breeds corruption, and after a point it plagues the rest of
the society. Inclusive states enable everyone to take part in the governance of
institutions and society and provide access to economic opportunity for
all.
Leaders in the U.S.
should be alarmed by the growing concentration of wealth, increasing corruption
in business and among public officials, declining growth rate, high
unemployment and under employment, declining wages and the gradual decline of
the middle class.
Mathur
is former chairman and professor of economics and now professor emeritus,
Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, Cleveland, Ohio. He also writes blogs for
the Standard-Examiner at http://blogs.standard.net/economics,etc.
No comments:
Post a Comment